fbpx
Wikipedia

Audience cost

An audience cost, in international relations theory, is the domestic political cost that leaders incur from their constituency if they escalate a foreign policy crisis and are then seen as backing down.[1][2][3] It is considered to be one of the potential mechanisms for democratic peace theory. It is associated with rational choice scholarship in international relations.

The implication of audience costs is that threats issued by leaders, who incur audience costs, against other states are more likely to be seen as credible and thus lead those states to meet the demands of the leader who makes threats.[4][5]

Democratic peace theory edit

The term was popularized in a 1994 academic article by James Fearon in which he argued that democracies carry greater audience costs than authoritarian states, which makes them better at signaling their intentions in interstate disputes.[6][7][8] It is one of the mechanisms for democratic peace theory.

Fearon's argument regarding the credibility of democratic states in disputes has been subject to debate among international relations scholars. Two studies 2001, using the MID and ICB datasets, provided empirical support for the notion that democracies were more likely to issue effective threats.[9][10] Survey experiment data substantiate that specified threats induce audience costs,[11][12][13] but other data have mixed findings[14] and nuanced findings.[15] A 2019 study found that audiences across the partisan divide had punished Trump, Obama, and "The President" for backing down after issuing threats, but it also found that presidents could reduce the audience costs by justifying the backing down as being in the national interest of the United States.[16] Erik Gartzke and Yonatan Lupu argue that the nature of audience costs (they are a mechanism, not an effect) makes them hard to detect empirically.[17] Kenneth Schultz has also remarked on the methodological difficulties in empirically assessing audience costs.[18] A major problem in assessing audience costs is the fact that leaders typically make threats that are ambiguous in terms of time, place, specific action that trigger the threat, and nature of response.[19] A smoking gun case for audience costs would be a case of the public opposing military action but subsequently punishing a leader for not going through with a threat to engage in military action.[19]

Branislav Slantchev, Matthew Baum and Philip Potter have argued that the presence of the free media is a key component of audience costs.[20][21] According to Matthew S. Levendusky, and Michael C. Horowitz, leaders can provide justifications to their audiences for why they backed down from a threat, thus reducing the audience costs.[22]

Roseanne McManus finds support for the existence of audience costs but argues that the credibility of a threat necessarily also relies on the threatener's military strength, hawkishness of domestic veto players, and leaders' security in office.[23]

Criticisms edit

However, a 2012 study by Alexander B. Downes and Todd S. Sechser found that existing datasets were not suitable to draw any conclusions as to whether democratic states issued more effective threats.[4] They constructed their own dataset specifically for interstate military threats and outcomes, which found no relationship between regime type and effective threats.[4] A 2017 study that recoded flaws in the MID dataset ultimately concluded " that there are no regime-based differences in dispute reciprocation, and prior findings may be based largely on poorly coded data."[24] Other scholars have disputed the democratic credibility argument and questioned its causal logic and empirical validity.[19] Jack Snyder and Erica Borghard argue that there is no evidence of audience costs in any post-1945 crises, leaders rarely make unambiguous threats, publics care about policy substance (not leader consistency in rhetoric and action), and publics care about the country's honor (not whether the leader issued an explicit threat).[19] They add that in cases of audience costs being observed, it is frequently when the public is hawkish and pushes leaders to adopt hardline stances and actions. It is unclear whether the domestic costs in those cases is because leaders fear getting caught bluffing, or they just do not want to defy a hawkish public.[19]

A 2021 study found that Americans perceived democracies to be more likely to back down in crises, which contradicts the expectations of the audience costs literature.[25] A 2011 study argued that domestic audiences in democratic states were less capable of punishing leaders for backing down because democratic leaders have larger "winning coalitions."[26] A 2012 study by Marc Trachtenberg, which analyzed a dozen great power crises, found no evidence of the presence of audience costs in these crises.[27]

A 2005 study, which used a formal bargaining model, found that in situations of both sides issuing public threats, a "prisoner's dilemma is created in which both sides make high public demands which cannot be satisfied, and both negotiators would be better off if they could commit to not making public demands."[28]

According to a 2021 study by Jayme R. Schlesinger and Jack S. Levy, leaders may be unaware of audience costs. To the extent that audience costs work, that may be a learned practice, rather than a consistent and timeless feature of international politics.[5]

Research by Jessica Weeks argued that some authoritarian regime types have similar audience costs as in democratic states.[29][30] Research by Jessica Chen Weiss argued that the Chinese regime fomented or clamped down on nationalist (or anti-foreign) protests in China to signal resolve. Fomenting or permitting nationalist protests entail audience costs, as they make it harder for the Chinese regime to back down in a foreign policy crisis out of fear of the protestors turning against the regime.[31]

Secret negotiations edit

Some scholars have grappled with the relationship between secret negotiations and audience costs. Shuhei Kurizaki,[32] Austin Carson,[33] Keren Yarhi-Milo,[34] and Levenotoglu and Tarar[28] have argued that secret operations, threats, and agreements can reduce inadvertent escalation to war by insulating leaders from the domestic backlash that would have occurred if the diplomacy had been conducted in public. Austin Carson argues that covert operations allow states to pursue their foreign policy interests without risking escalation to war. By keeping the operation covert, states avoid pressure by domestic audiences to escalate the operation beyond their original intent and communicate to their adversary their intent to keep the operation limited.[33] Keren Yarhi-Milo argues that secret agreements between adversaries can lead to lasting peace if their initiator faces domestic opposition to the terms of the agreement. The ability of the other state to publicly disclose the terms means that it is a form of costly signaling of intentions by the initiator.[34]

In other contexts edit

States may be more likely to honor alliance commitments because of audience costs.[35]

According to a 2020 study by Joshua A. Schwartz and Christopher W. Blair, gender stereotypes about leaders lead to audience costs, as women leaders are punished more severely for backing down after issuing threats.[36]

A 2006 study by Todd Allee and Paul Huth found that leaders try to avoid audience costs for voluntary-negotiated settlements by instead using rulings by an international court or arbitration body, which the leaders can blame for adverse outcomes.[37]

A 2020 study by John Harden explored some links between narcissistic leaders and audience cost theory. Narcissistic leaders can, in some cases, exploit audience costs to force uncooperative branches of government into action by swinging public opinion. [38]

References edit

  1. ^ "Audience Costs and the Credibility of Commitments", International Relations, Oxford University Press, 2021, doi:10.1093/obo/9780199743292-0305, ISBN 978-0-19-974329-2
  2. ^ James Fearon (7 September 2013). "'Credibility' is not everything but it's not nothing either". The Monkey Cage. Retrieved 8 January 2014. I'm drawing here on arguments about what the IR literature usually calls 'audience costs', which are domestic political costs a leader may pay for escalating an international dispute, or for making implicit or explicit threats, and then backing down or not following through.
  3. ^ Trager, Robert F. (2016). "The Diplomacy of War and Peace". Annual Review of Political Science. 19 (1): 205–228. doi:10.1146/annurev-polisci-051214-100534. ISSN 1094-2939.
  4. ^ a b c Downes, Alexander B.; Sechser, Todd S. (2012). "The Illusion of Democratic Credibility". International Organization. 66 (3): 457–489. doi:10.1017/S0020818312000161. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 23279964. S2CID 154325372.
  5. ^ a b Schlesinger, Jayme R.; Levy, Jack S. (2021). "Politics, audience costs, and signalling: Britain and the 1863–4 Schleswig-Holstein crisis". European Journal of International Security. 6 (3): 338–357. doi:10.1017/eis.2021.7. ISSN 2057-5637.
  6. ^ Fearon, James D. (September 1994). "Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Dispute". American Political Science Review. 88 (3): 577–592. doi:10.2307/2944796. JSTOR 2944796. S2CID 36315471.
  7. ^ Schultz, Kenneth A. (2012). "Why We Needed Audience Costs and What We Need Now". Security Studies. 21 (3): 369–375. doi:10.1080/09636412.2012.706475. ISSN 0963-6412. S2CID 153373634.
  8. ^ Tomz, Michael (2007). "Domestic Audience Costs in International Relations: An Experimental Approach". International Organization. 61 (4): 821–40. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.386.7495. doi:10.1017/S0020818307070282. ISSN 0020-8183. S2CID 154895678. The seminal article is Fearon 1994.
  9. ^ Schultz, Kenneth A. (2001). Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy. Cambridge Studies in International Relations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511491658. ISBN 978-0-521-79227-1.
  10. ^ Gelpi, Christopher F.; Griesdorf, Michael (2001). "Winners or Losers? Democracies in International Crisis, 1918–94". American Political Science Review. 95 (3): 633–647. doi:10.1017/S0003055401003148. ISSN 0003-0554. S2CID 146346368.
  11. ^ Trager, Robert F.; Vavreck, Lynn (2011). "The Political Costs of Crisis Bargaining: Presidential Rhetoric and the Role of Party". American Journal of Political Science. 55 (3): 526–545. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2011.00521.x. ISSN 1540-5907.
  12. ^ Levy, Jack S.; McKoy, Michael K.; Poast, Paul; Wallace, Geoffrey P. R. (2015). "Backing Out or Backing In? Commitment and Consistency in Audience Costs Theory". American Journal of Political Science. 59 (4): 988–1001. doi:10.1111/ajps.12197. ISSN 1540-5907.
  13. ^ Tomz, Michael (2007). "Domestic Audience Costs in International Relations: An Experimental Approach". International Organization. 61 (4): 821–840. doi:10.1017/S0020818307070282. ISSN 1531-5088. S2CID 154895678.
  14. ^ Kertzer, Joshua D.; Brutger, Ryan (2016). "Decomposing Audience Costs: Bringing the Audience Back into Audience Cost Theory". American Journal of Political Science. 60 (1): 234–249. doi:10.1111/ajps.12201. ISSN 1540-5907.
  15. ^ Brutger, Ryan; Kertzer, Joshua D. (2018). "A Dispositional Theory of Reputation Costs". International Organization. 72 (3): 693–724. doi:10.1017/S0020818318000188. ISSN 0020-8183. S2CID 149511346.
  16. ^ Evers, Miles M.; Fisher, Aleksandr; Schaaf, Steven D. (2019). "Is There a Trump Effect? An Experiment on Political Polarization and Audience Costs". Perspectives on Politics. 17 (2): 433–452. doi:10.1017/S1537592718003390. ISSN 1537-5927. S2CID 181670458.
  17. ^ Gartzke, Erik; Lupu, Yonatan (2012). "Still Looking for Audience Costs". Security Studies. 21 (3): 391–397. doi:10.1080/09636412.2012.706486. ISSN 0963-6412. S2CID 219715939.
  18. ^ Schultz, Kenneth A. (2001). "Looking for Audience Costs". The Journal of Conflict Resolution. 45 (1): 32–60. doi:10.1177/0022002701045001002. ISSN 0022-0027. JSTOR 3176282. S2CID 146554967.
  19. ^ a b c d e Snyder, Jack; Borghard, Erica D. (2011). "The Cost of Empty Threats: A Penny, Not a Pound". American Political Science Review. 105 (3): 437–456. doi:10.1017/s000305541100027x. ISSN 0003-0554. S2CID 144584619.
  20. ^ Slantchev, Branislav L. (2006). "Politicians, the Media, and Domestic Audience Costs". International Studies Quarterly. 50 (2): 445–477. doi:10.1111/j.1468-2478.2006.00409.x. ISSN 0020-8833. JSTOR 3693618. S2CID 29056557.
  21. ^ Potter, Philip B. K.; Baum, Matthew A. (2014). "Looking for Audience Costs in all the Wrong Places: Electoral Institutions, Media Access, and Democratic Constraint". The Journal of Politics. 76 (1): 167–181. doi:10.1017/S0022381613001230. ISSN 0022-3816. S2CID 39535209.
  22. ^ Levendusky, Matthew S.; Horowitz, Michael C. (2012). "When Backing Down Is the Right Decision: Partisanship, New Information, and Audience Costs". The Journal of Politics. 74 (2): 323–338. doi:10.1017/S002238161100154X. ISSN 0022-3816.
  23. ^ McManus, Roseanne W. (2017). Statements of Resolve: Achieving Coercive Credibility in International Conflict. Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/9781316756263. ISBN 978-1-107-17034-6.
  24. ^ Gibler, Douglas M.; Miller, Steven V.; Little, Erin K. (2016-12-01). "An Analysis of the Militarized Interstate Dispute (MID) Dataset, 1816–2001". International Studies Quarterly. 60 (4): 719–730. doi:10.1093/isq/sqw045. ISSN 0020-8833. S2CID 151567567.
  25. ^ Kertzer, Joshua D.; Renshon, Jonathan; Yarhi-Milo, Keren (2021). "How Do Observers Assess Resolve?". British Journal of Political Science. 51 (1): 308–330. doi:10.1017/S0007123418000595. ISSN 0007-1234. S2CID 197463343.
  26. ^ Brown, Jonathan N.; Marcum, Anthony S. (2011). "Avoiding Audience Costs: Domestic Political Accountability and Concessions in Crisis Diplomacy". Security Studies. 20 (2): 141–170. doi:10.1080/09636412.2011.572671. ISSN 0963-6412. S2CID 144555729.
  27. ^ Trachtenberg, Marc (2012). "Audience Costs: An Historical Analysis". Security Studies. 21 (1): 3–42. doi:10.1080/09636412.2012.650590. ISSN 0963-6412. S2CID 145647675.
  28. ^ a b Levenotoğlu, Bahar; Tarar, Ahmer (2005). "Prenegotiation Public Commitment in Domestic and International Bargaining". American Political Science Review. 99 (3): 419–433. doi:10.1017/S0003055405051750. hdl:10161/2534. ISSN 1537-5943. S2CID 16072285.
  29. ^ Weeks, Jessica L. (2008). "Autocratic Audience Costs: Regime Type and Signaling Resolve". International Organization. 62 (1): 35–64. doi:10.1017/S0020818308080028. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 40071874. S2CID 154432066.
  30. ^ Weeks, Jessica L. P. (2014). Dictators at War and Peace. Cornell University Press. ISBN 978-0-8014-5296-3. JSTOR 10.7591/j.ctt1287f18.
  31. ^ Weiss, Jessica Chen (2014). Powerful Patriots: Nationalist Protest in China's Foreign Relations. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-938757-1.
  32. ^ Kurizaki, Shuhei (2007). "Efficient Secrecy: Public versus Private Threats in Crisis Diplomacy". American Political Science Review. 101 (3): 543–558. doi:10.1017/S0003055407070396. ISSN 1537-5943. S2CID 154793333.
  33. ^ a b Carson, Austin (2018). Secret Wars: Covert Conflict in International Politics. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-18176-9.
  34. ^ a b Yarhi-Milo, Keren (2013). "Tying Hands Behind Closed Doors: The Logic and Practice of Secret Reassurance". Security Studies. 22 (3): 405–435. doi:10.1080/09636412.2013.816126. ISSN 0963-6412. S2CID 153936013.
  35. ^ Morrow, James D. (2000). "Alliances: Why Write Them Down?". Annual Review of Political Science. 3 (1): 63–83. doi:10.1146/annurev.polisci.3.1.63. ISSN 1094-2939.
  36. ^ Schwartz, Joshua A.; Blair, Christopher W. (2020). "Do Women Make More Credible Threats? Gender Stereotypes, Audience Costs, and Crisis Bargaining". International Organization. 74 (4): 872–895. doi:10.1017/S0020818320000223. ISSN 0020-8183. S2CID 225735033.
  37. ^ Allee, Todd L.; Huth, Paul K. (2006). "Legitimizing Dispute Settlement: International Legal Rulings as Domestic Political Cover". American Political Science Review. 100 (2): 219–234. doi:10.1017/S0003055406062125. ISSN 1537-5943. S2CID 145146053.
  38. ^ Harden, John P. (2021). "All The World's a Stage: US Presidential Narcissism and International Conflict". International Studies Quarterly. 65 (3): 825–837. doi:10.1093/isq/sqab048. ISSN 1094-2939.

audience, cost, audience, cost, international, relations, theory, domestic, political, cost, that, leaders, incur, from, their, constituency, they, escalate, foreign, policy, crisis, then, seen, backing, down, considered, potential, mechanisms, democratic, pea. An audience cost in international relations theory is the domestic political cost that leaders incur from their constituency if they escalate a foreign policy crisis and are then seen as backing down 1 2 3 It is considered to be one of the potential mechanisms for democratic peace theory It is associated with rational choice scholarship in international relations The implication of audience costs is that threats issued by leaders who incur audience costs against other states are more likely to be seen as credible and thus lead those states to meet the demands of the leader who makes threats 4 5 Contents 1 Democratic peace theory 1 1 Criticisms 2 Secret negotiations 3 In other contexts 4 ReferencesDemocratic peace theory editMain article Democratic peace theory The term was popularized in a 1994 academic article by James Fearon in which he argued that democracies carry greater audience costs than authoritarian states which makes them better at signaling their intentions in interstate disputes 6 7 8 It is one of the mechanisms for democratic peace theory Fearon s argument regarding the credibility of democratic states in disputes has been subject to debate among international relations scholars Two studies 2001 using the MID and ICB datasets provided empirical support for the notion that democracies were more likely to issue effective threats 9 10 Survey experiment data substantiate that specified threats induce audience costs 11 12 13 but other data have mixed findings 14 and nuanced findings 15 A 2019 study found that audiences across the partisan divide had punished Trump Obama and The President for backing down after issuing threats but it also found that presidents could reduce the audience costs by justifying the backing down as being in the national interest of the United States 16 Erik Gartzke and Yonatan Lupu argue that the nature of audience costs they are a mechanism not an effect makes them hard to detect empirically 17 Kenneth Schultz has also remarked on the methodological difficulties in empirically assessing audience costs 18 A major problem in assessing audience costs is the fact that leaders typically make threats that are ambiguous in terms of time place specific action that trigger the threat and nature of response 19 A smoking gun case for audience costs would be a case of the public opposing military action but subsequently punishing a leader for not going through with a threat to engage in military action 19 Branislav Slantchev Matthew Baum and Philip Potter have argued that the presence of the free media is a key component of audience costs 20 21 According to Matthew S Levendusky and Michael C Horowitz leaders can provide justifications to their audiences for why they backed down from a threat thus reducing the audience costs 22 Roseanne McManus finds support for the existence of audience costs but argues that the credibility of a threat necessarily also relies on the threatener s military strength hawkishness of domestic veto players and leaders security in office 23 Criticisms edit However a 2012 study by Alexander B Downes and Todd S Sechser found that existing datasets were not suitable to draw any conclusions as to whether democratic states issued more effective threats 4 They constructed their own dataset specifically for interstate military threats and outcomes which found no relationship between regime type and effective threats 4 A 2017 study that recoded flaws in the MID dataset ultimately concluded that there are no regime based differences in dispute reciprocation and prior findings may be based largely on poorly coded data 24 Other scholars have disputed the democratic credibility argument and questioned its causal logic and empirical validity 19 Jack Snyder and Erica Borghard argue that there is no evidence of audience costs in any post 1945 crises leaders rarely make unambiguous threats publics care about policy substance not leader consistency in rhetoric and action and publics care about the country s honor not whether the leader issued an explicit threat 19 They add that in cases of audience costs being observed it is frequently when the public is hawkish and pushes leaders to adopt hardline stances and actions It is unclear whether the domestic costs in those cases is because leaders fear getting caught bluffing or they just do not want to defy a hawkish public 19 A 2021 study found that Americans perceived democracies to be more likely to back down in crises which contradicts the expectations of the audience costs literature 25 A 2011 study argued that domestic audiences in democratic states were less capable of punishing leaders for backing down because democratic leaders have larger winning coalitions 26 A 2012 study by Marc Trachtenberg which analyzed a dozen great power crises found no evidence of the presence of audience costs in these crises 27 A 2005 study which used a formal bargaining model found that in situations of both sides issuing public threats a prisoner s dilemma is created in which both sides make high public demands which cannot be satisfied and both negotiators would be better off if they could commit to not making public demands 28 According to a 2021 study by Jayme R Schlesinger and Jack S Levy leaders may be unaware of audience costs To the extent that audience costs work that may be a learned practice rather than a consistent and timeless feature of international politics 5 Research by Jessica Weeks argued that some authoritarian regime types have similar audience costs as in democratic states 29 30 Research by Jessica Chen Weiss argued that the Chinese regime fomented or clamped down on nationalist or anti foreign protests in China to signal resolve Fomenting or permitting nationalist protests entail audience costs as they make it harder for the Chinese regime to back down in a foreign policy crisis out of fear of the protestors turning against the regime 31 Secret negotiations editSome scholars have grappled with the relationship between secret negotiations and audience costs Shuhei Kurizaki 32 Austin Carson 33 Keren Yarhi Milo 34 and Levenotoglu and Tarar 28 have argued that secret operations threats and agreements can reduce inadvertent escalation to war by insulating leaders from the domestic backlash that would have occurred if the diplomacy had been conducted in public Austin Carson argues that covert operations allow states to pursue their foreign policy interests without risking escalation to war By keeping the operation covert states avoid pressure by domestic audiences to escalate the operation beyond their original intent and communicate to their adversary their intent to keep the operation limited 33 Keren Yarhi Milo argues that secret agreements between adversaries can lead to lasting peace if their initiator faces domestic opposition to the terms of the agreement The ability of the other state to publicly disclose the terms means that it is a form of costly signaling of intentions by the initiator 34 In other contexts editStates may be more likely to honor alliance commitments because of audience costs 35 According to a 2020 study by Joshua A Schwartz and Christopher W Blair gender stereotypes about leaders lead to audience costs as women leaders are punished more severely for backing down after issuing threats 36 A 2006 study by Todd Allee and Paul Huth found that leaders try to avoid audience costs for voluntary negotiated settlements by instead using rulings by an international court or arbitration body which the leaders can blame for adverse outcomes 37 A 2020 study by John Harden explored some links between narcissistic leaders and audience cost theory Narcissistic leaders can in some cases exploit audience costs to force uncooperative branches of government into action by swinging public opinion 38 References edit Audience Costs and the Credibility of Commitments International Relations Oxford University Press 2021 doi 10 1093 obo 9780199743292 0305 ISBN 978 0 19 974329 2 James Fearon 7 September 2013 Credibility is not everything but it s not nothing either The Monkey Cage Retrieved 8 January 2014 I m drawing here on arguments about what the IR literature usually calls audience costs which are domestic political costs a leader may pay for escalating an international dispute or for making implicit or explicit threats and then backing down or not following through Trager Robert F 2016 The Diplomacy of War and Peace Annual Review of Political Science 19 1 205 228 doi 10 1146 annurev polisci 051214 100534 ISSN 1094 2939 a b c Downes Alexander B Sechser Todd S 2012 The Illusion of Democratic Credibility International Organization 66 3 457 489 doi 10 1017 S0020818312000161 ISSN 0020 8183 JSTOR 23279964 S2CID 154325372 a b Schlesinger Jayme R Levy Jack S 2021 Politics audience costs and signalling Britain and the 1863 4 Schleswig Holstein crisis European Journal of International Security 6 3 338 357 doi 10 1017 eis 2021 7 ISSN 2057 5637 Fearon James D September 1994 Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Dispute American Political Science Review 88 3 577 592 doi 10 2307 2944796 JSTOR 2944796 S2CID 36315471 Schultz Kenneth A 2012 Why We Needed Audience Costs and What We Need Now Security Studies 21 3 369 375 doi 10 1080 09636412 2012 706475 ISSN 0963 6412 S2CID 153373634 Tomz Michael 2007 Domestic Audience Costs in International Relations An Experimental Approach International Organization 61 4 821 40 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 386 7495 doi 10 1017 S0020818307070282 ISSN 0020 8183 S2CID 154895678 The seminal article is Fearon 1994 Schultz Kenneth A 2001 Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy Cambridge Studies in International Relations Cambridge Cambridge University Press doi 10 1017 cbo9780511491658 ISBN 978 0 521 79227 1 Gelpi Christopher F Griesdorf Michael 2001 Winners or Losers Democracies in International Crisis 1918 94 American Political Science Review 95 3 633 647 doi 10 1017 S0003055401003148 ISSN 0003 0554 S2CID 146346368 Trager Robert F Vavreck Lynn 2011 The Political Costs of Crisis Bargaining Presidential Rhetoric and the Role of Party American Journal of Political Science 55 3 526 545 doi 10 1111 j 1540 5907 2011 00521 x ISSN 1540 5907 Levy Jack S McKoy Michael K Poast Paul Wallace Geoffrey P R 2015 Backing Out or Backing In Commitment and Consistency in Audience Costs Theory American Journal of Political Science 59 4 988 1001 doi 10 1111 ajps 12197 ISSN 1540 5907 Tomz Michael 2007 Domestic Audience Costs in International Relations An Experimental Approach International Organization 61 4 821 840 doi 10 1017 S0020818307070282 ISSN 1531 5088 S2CID 154895678 Kertzer Joshua D Brutger Ryan 2016 Decomposing Audience Costs Bringing the Audience Back into Audience Cost Theory American Journal of Political Science 60 1 234 249 doi 10 1111 ajps 12201 ISSN 1540 5907 Brutger Ryan Kertzer Joshua D 2018 A Dispositional Theory of Reputation Costs International Organization 72 3 693 724 doi 10 1017 S0020818318000188 ISSN 0020 8183 S2CID 149511346 Evers Miles M Fisher Aleksandr Schaaf Steven D 2019 Is There a Trump Effect An Experiment on Political Polarization and Audience Costs Perspectives on Politics 17 2 433 452 doi 10 1017 S1537592718003390 ISSN 1537 5927 S2CID 181670458 Gartzke Erik Lupu Yonatan 2012 Still Looking for Audience Costs Security Studies 21 3 391 397 doi 10 1080 09636412 2012 706486 ISSN 0963 6412 S2CID 219715939 Schultz Kenneth A 2001 Looking for Audience Costs The Journal of Conflict Resolution 45 1 32 60 doi 10 1177 0022002701045001002 ISSN 0022 0027 JSTOR 3176282 S2CID 146554967 a b c d e Snyder Jack Borghard Erica D 2011 The Cost of Empty Threats A Penny Not a Pound American Political Science Review 105 3 437 456 doi 10 1017 s000305541100027x ISSN 0003 0554 S2CID 144584619 Slantchev Branislav L 2006 Politicians the Media and Domestic Audience Costs International Studies Quarterly 50 2 445 477 doi 10 1111 j 1468 2478 2006 00409 x ISSN 0020 8833 JSTOR 3693618 S2CID 29056557 Potter Philip B K Baum Matthew A 2014 Looking for Audience Costs in all the Wrong Places Electoral Institutions Media Access and Democratic Constraint The Journal of Politics 76 1 167 181 doi 10 1017 S0022381613001230 ISSN 0022 3816 S2CID 39535209 Levendusky Matthew S Horowitz Michael C 2012 When Backing Down Is the Right Decision Partisanship New Information and Audience Costs The Journal of Politics 74 2 323 338 doi 10 1017 S002238161100154X ISSN 0022 3816 McManus Roseanne W 2017 Statements of Resolve Achieving Coercive Credibility in International Conflict Cambridge University Press doi 10 1017 9781316756263 ISBN 978 1 107 17034 6 Gibler Douglas M Miller Steven V Little Erin K 2016 12 01 An Analysis of the Militarized Interstate Dispute MID Dataset 1816 2001 International Studies Quarterly 60 4 719 730 doi 10 1093 isq sqw045 ISSN 0020 8833 S2CID 151567567 Kertzer Joshua D Renshon Jonathan Yarhi Milo Keren 2021 How Do Observers Assess Resolve British Journal of Political Science 51 1 308 330 doi 10 1017 S0007123418000595 ISSN 0007 1234 S2CID 197463343 Brown Jonathan N Marcum Anthony S 2011 Avoiding Audience Costs Domestic Political Accountability and Concessions in Crisis Diplomacy Security Studies 20 2 141 170 doi 10 1080 09636412 2011 572671 ISSN 0963 6412 S2CID 144555729 Trachtenberg Marc 2012 Audience Costs An Historical Analysis Security Studies 21 1 3 42 doi 10 1080 09636412 2012 650590 ISSN 0963 6412 S2CID 145647675 a b Levenotoglu Bahar Tarar Ahmer 2005 Prenegotiation Public Commitment in Domestic and International Bargaining American Political Science Review 99 3 419 433 doi 10 1017 S0003055405051750 hdl 10161 2534 ISSN 1537 5943 S2CID 16072285 Weeks Jessica L 2008 Autocratic Audience Costs Regime Type and Signaling Resolve International Organization 62 1 35 64 doi 10 1017 S0020818308080028 ISSN 0020 8183 JSTOR 40071874 S2CID 154432066 Weeks Jessica L P 2014 Dictators at War and Peace Cornell University Press ISBN 978 0 8014 5296 3 JSTOR 10 7591 j ctt1287f18 Weiss Jessica Chen 2014 Powerful Patriots Nationalist Protest in China s Foreign Relations Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 938757 1 Kurizaki Shuhei 2007 Efficient Secrecy Public versus Private Threats in Crisis Diplomacy American Political Science Review 101 3 543 558 doi 10 1017 S0003055407070396 ISSN 1537 5943 S2CID 154793333 a b Carson Austin 2018 Secret Wars Covert Conflict in International Politics Princeton University Press ISBN 978 0 691 18176 9 a b Yarhi Milo Keren 2013 Tying Hands Behind Closed Doors The Logic and Practice of Secret Reassurance Security Studies 22 3 405 435 doi 10 1080 09636412 2013 816126 ISSN 0963 6412 S2CID 153936013 Morrow James D 2000 Alliances Why Write Them Down Annual Review of Political Science 3 1 63 83 doi 10 1146 annurev polisci 3 1 63 ISSN 1094 2939 Schwartz Joshua A Blair Christopher W 2020 Do Women Make More Credible Threats Gender Stereotypes Audience Costs and Crisis Bargaining International Organization 74 4 872 895 doi 10 1017 S0020818320000223 ISSN 0020 8183 S2CID 225735033 Allee Todd L Huth Paul K 2006 Legitimizing Dispute Settlement International Legal Rulings as Domestic Political Cover American Political Science Review 100 2 219 234 doi 10 1017 S0003055406062125 ISSN 1537 5943 S2CID 145146053 Harden John P 2021 All The World s a Stage US Presidential Narcissism and International Conflict International Studies Quarterly 65 3 825 837 doi 10 1093 isq sqab048 ISSN 1094 2939 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Audience cost amp oldid 1189472619, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.